fbpx
01 / 05
Romer and Nordhaus: Worthy Nobel Winners

Blog Post | Economic Growth

Romer and Nordhaus: Worthy Nobel Winners

Nordhaus showed that the price of light collapsed as a result of innovation. Romer showed that human potential for innovation is infinite.

World in the palm of hands of Nobel winners

On Monday, William Nordhaus and Paul Romer were awarded the Nobel Prize in Economics. Nordhaus, the Sterling Professor of Economics at Yale University, is best known for his work in economic modelling and climate change. Romer, who teaches at New York University, is a pioneer of endogenous growth theory, which holds that investment in human capital, innovation, and knowledge are significant contributors to economic growth.

The two American economists’ research is vital in showing the way people underestimate the progress humanity has already made and the likelihood that it will continue well into the future.

In his 1996 paper, Do Real-Output and Real-Wage Measures Capture Reality? The History of Lighting Suggests Not, Nordhaus looked at the economics of light. Open fire, he noted, produced a mere 0.00235 lumens per watt (a lumen is a measure of how much visible light is emitted by a source.) Lumens per watt refers to the energy efficiency of lighting. A traditional 60 watt incandescent bulb, for example, produces 860 lumens.

A sesame lamp could produce 0.0597 lumens per watt; a sperm tallow candle 0.1009 lumens; whale oil 0.1346 lumens and an early town gaslamp 0.2464 lumens. An electric filament lamp, which was launched in 1883, achieved an unbelievable 2.6 lumens per watt and, due to subsequent technological improvements, managed to deliver an astonishing 14.1667 lumens by 1990. Yet that’s small beer compared to the compact fluorescent lightbulb, which delivered 68.2778 lumens per watt when it was launched in 1992.

William Nordhaus

Accompanying these amazing improvements in the efficiency of lighting was a collapse in its price, both in absolute terms and in terms of human labour. Nordhaus estimates that the price of light per 1,000 lumens was $785 in 1800. By 1992 that price had dropped to 23 cents (both figures are in 2018 dollars). That amounts to a reduction of 99.97 percent. Today, the monetary cost of lighting per 1,000 lumens is inconsequential.

Now, consider the price of lighting from the perspective of human labour. Prior to the Neolithic revolution, which put an end to our nomadic past and turned our species into agriculturalists, it took more than 50 hours of labor (mostly gathering wood) to “buy” 1,000 lumen hours of light. By 1800, it took about 5.4 hours.

By 1900, it took 0.22 hours. By 1992, 1,000 lumen hours required 0.00012 hours of human labor. That amounts to a reduction of close to 100 per cent. As Tyler Cowen of George Mason University noted, Nordhaus found that “GDP figures understate the true extent of growth, and show[ed] that the relative price of bringing light to humans has fallen more rapidly than GDP growth figures alone might indicate.”

Put differently, technological change, which is not fully captured in GDP figures, makes us underappreciate the tremendous advance in standards of living over that of our ancestors. Can that advance be sustained and, even, improved upon? That’s where Romer enters the picture.

Many people worry that rising standards of living are unsustainable. Economic growth, they fear, will lead to exhaustion of natural resources and civilisational collapse. Just last year, Stanford University biology professor Paul R. Ehrlich noted that “You can’t go on growing forever on a finite planet. The biggest problem we face is the continued expansion of the human enterprise … Perpetual growth is the creed of a cancer cell.”

The earth, it is true, is a closed system. One day, we might be able to replenish our resources from outer space by, for example, dragging a mineral-rich asteroid down to Earth. In the meantime, we have to make do with the resources we have. But, what exactly do we have?

Paul Romer

According to Romer, we do not know the full extent of our resources. That’s because what matters is not the total number of atoms on Earth, but the infinite number of ways in which those atoms can be combined and recombined. As he put it in his 2015 article “Economic Growth”:

Every generation has perceived the limits to growth that finite resources and undesirable side effects would pose if no new recipes or ideas were discovered. And every generation has underestimated the potential for finding new recipes and ideas. We consistently fail to grasp how many ideas remain to be discovered.

The difficulty is the same one we have with compounding. Possibilities do not add up. They multiply.… To get some sense of how much scope there is for more such discoveries, we can calculate as follows. The periodic table contains about a hundred different types of atoms. If a recipe is simply an indication of whether an element is included or not, there will be 100 x 99 recipes like the one for bronze or steel that involve only two elements. For recipes that can have four elements, there are 100 x 99 x 98 x 97 recipes, which is more 94 million. With up to five elements, more than 9 billion. Mathematicians call this increase in the number of combinations ‘combinatorial explosion.

Once you get to 10 elements, there are more recipes than seconds since the big bang created the universe. As you keep going, it becomes obvious that there have been too few people on earth and too little time since we showed up, for us to have tried more than a minuscule fraction of the all the possibilities.

Figuring out the availability of resources, therefore, is not about measuring the quantity of resources, as engineers do. It is about looking at the prices of resources, as economists do. In a competitive economy, humanity’s knowledge about the value of something tends to be reflected in its price. As new knowledge emerges, prices change accordingly.

Nordhaus showed that the price of light collapsed as a result of innovation. Romer showed that human potential for innovation is infinite. The two men are apostles of human progress and well deserving of the highest accolade that the discipline of economics can bestow.

Curiosities | Cost of Living

The Real Reasons Your Appliances Die Young

“Many people have a memory of some ancient, avocado-green washing machine or refrigerator chugging along for decades at their grandparents’ house. But even then, decade-spanning durability was uncommon.

Although I couldn’t find a ton of hard data on appliance lifespan over the past 40 years, nearly everyone I spoke with — service technicians, designers, engineers, trade-organization representatives, salespeople — said that kind of longevity was always the outlier, not the norm.

‘Everybody talks about the Maytag washing machine that lasts 50 years,’ said Daniel Conrad, a former product engineer at Whirlpool Corporation who is now the director of design quality, reliability, and testing for a commercial-refrigeration company. ‘No one talks about the other 4.5 million that didn’t last that long.'”

From New York Times.

Blog Post | Cost of Material Goods

From Silk Stockings to Synthetic Diamonds

Capitalist innovation makes luxury commonplace.

Summary: The economist Joseph Schumpeter explained capitalism’s power to transform luxuries for the elite into affordable goods for the masses. From silk stockings once reserved for queens to synthetic diamonds now within reach of everyday consumers, capitalist innovation drives this democratization of consumption.


In his 1942 book Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, the Austrian economist Joseph Schumpeter explained one of the most important characteristics of free market economies. He wrote:

It is the cheap cloth, the cheap cotton and rayon fabric, boots, motorcars and so on that are the typical achievements of capitalist production, and not as a rule improvements that would mean much to the rich man. Queen Elizabeth owned silk stockings. The capitalist achievement does not typically consist in providing more silk stockings for queens but in bringing them within the reach of factory girls.

Schumpeter’s anecdote about Queen Elizabeth and silk stockings illustrates capitalism’s remarkable ability to democratize consumption.

Initially, silk stockings symbolized privilege reserved only for royalty and elites. Yet capitalism’s true achievement, Schumpeter argued, is not merely supplying luxury to the rich but making such goods affordable for ordinary people. Entrepreneurial innovation, mass production, competition, and technological advances – driven by profit incentives – bring previously unattainable products within everyone’s reach.

This phenomenon elevates the living standards of the less fortunate by breaking down class barriers and spreading prosperity more broadly. Capitalism’s transformative force, according to Schumpeter, lies in continually converting luxuries into everyday essentials, thereby enhancing human well-being across social strata.

The diamond industry today exemplifies Schumpeter’s insight perfectly. Historically, diamonds represented wealth and exclusivity, accessible primarily to the affluent. However, technological advancements, particularly synthetic diamond production via High Pressure High Temperature (HPHT) methods and Chemical Vapor Deposition (CVD) technology, have dramatically changed this dynamic.

Chemical Vapor Deposition (CVD), for example, is a technique for creating synthetic diamonds by depositing carbon atoms from a carbon-rich gas onto a substrate. In this method, a diamond seed crystal is placed in a vacuum chamber filled with gases such as methane and hydrogen. When heated to very high temperatures, these gases break down, and carbon atoms accumulate layer-by-layer on the seed crystal, slowly forming a diamond. This process enables precise control over diamond purity, size, and quality, making it highly efficient and cost-effective compared to traditional diamond mining methods.

Not only have synthetic diamonds become more widely affordable, but they have also placed a downward pressure on natural diamond prices. As a recent article in The Guardian explained:

Natural diamonds cost 26% less in shops than two years ago, a drop during a time of high inflation that would be extraordinary were it not dwarfed by the poor fortune of their identical twins, lab-grown diamonds, which are now 74% cheaper than in 2020.

Furthermore, synthetic diamonds may appeal to modern consumers by offering ethical and environmental advantages over mined diamonds. Instead of sourcing diamonds from some of the world’s bloodiest conflict zones marked by human rights abuses and environments destroyed by primitive forms of mining, today’s diamonds increasingly come from the lab.

Much like silk stockings transitioned from royal exclusivity to widespread accessibility, diamonds today are undergoing a similar evolution. Synthetic diamonds eliminate historical barriers of price, scarcity, and exclusivity, transforming diamonds from symbols of privilege into everyday commodities.

Blog Post | Cost of Living

Time Pricing Mark Perry’s Latest “Chart of the Century”

Always compare prices to hourly wages to understand the true change in living standards.

Professor Mark Perry recently posted his updated “Chart of the Century,” featuring price and wage data from the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS). The chart tracks 14 items over the 24 years from January 2000 to December 2024 and includes both the overall inflation rate and changes in average hourly wages.

To examine the data from a different perspective, we calculated the change in time prices of these 14 items relative to the change in the average hourly wage. We then determined the abundance multiplier—a value that indicates how many units of an item you could buy in 2024 for the amount of work time it took to buy one unit in 2000. If there were no change, the abundance multiplier would equal one. A value below one indicates decreasing abundance, while a value above one reflects increasing abundance. We also calculated the percentage change in abundance for each item.

This analysis illustrates that things can become more expensive in dollar terms while simultaneously becoming more affordable in time prices. For instance, while the general Consumer Price Index (CPI) rose by 87.3 percent, average hourly wages increased by 123.3 percent. As a result, time prices fell by 16.1 percent. For the time it took to purchase one CPI basket in January 2000, a consumer could buy 1.192 baskets in December 2024—an abundance increase of 19.2 percent.

Notably, categories such as housing, food and beverages, new cars, household furnishings, and clothing all increased in money prices. However, after adjusting for rising wages, they became more affordable in time-price terms. Although 10 of the 14 items rose in nominal prices over the 24 years, only five had a higher time price when accounting for the 123.3 percent increase in hourly wages.

We also created a chart showing the percentage change in abundance for the general CPI and each of the 14 tracked items:

Find more of Gale’s work at his Substack, Gale Winds.